Wednesday, December 02, 2009

initative anit minarets

POURQUOI ETES VOUS REVOLTéS ,le peuple est capable de bien pire. notre concitoyen Freysinger Oskar, un guillaume tell contemporain ou un taleban valaisan qui proclame la victoire de la liberté en écrasant grossièrement les droits fondamentaux des autres !! Moi je suis revolté par 24 mois d'échecs continus, d'être représenté par des ministres qui se sont révélés à la majorité des médiocres, même pas capables de fermer une initiative pareille au nom des libertés fondamentales ou au moins de la réorienter, qui renflouent les caisses d'une banque en faillite et refusent des crédits de 100 fois moins pour l'aide à la formation , qui traitent avec beacoup de respect un tyran qui guide san aucun droit son pays, la Lybie, et se baffoue des petits suisses symbolisés par notre cher président , un renard qui parle 7 langues , le russe aussi, mais ne pige rien de la politique des bédouins si éloignée du monde idéal qui est le notre, la Suisse.

Wednesday, November 18, 2009

painting

Dimitri Kozyrev (
alessandro roma
sonia almeida

http://images.google.ch/imgres?imgurl=http://certamenpintura.dipcas.es/upload/web/20081215154255.20071214101303.alessando%2520roma_italia.jpeg&imgrefurl=http://certamenpintura.dipcas.es/en/detalle_galeria.php%3Fid%3D4&usg=__yq4TYaXK_5pc2NJYZKlT7GvuMZ8=&h=600&w=540&sz=356&hl=fr&start=1&um=1&tbnid=wQGTlEiUJeQ-5M:&tbnh=135&tbnw=122&prev=/images%3Fq%3DAlessando%2BRoma%26hl%3Dfr%26rlz%3D1C1GGLS_frFR291CH305%26sa%3DN%26um%3D1

http://www.dimitrikozyrev.com/main.php

juergen grewe

http://www.juergengrewe.com/add.html

Friday, October 16, 2009

Saturday, September 26, 2009

lyrics chavela vargas

FLOR DE AZALEA
(Manuel Esperón / S. Gómez Urquiza)

Javier Solis (Mexico)


Como espuma que inerte lleva el caudaloso río
Flor de Azalea la vida en su avalancha te arrastró
pero al salvarte hallar pudiste protección y abrigo
donde curar tu corazón herido por el dolor

Tu sonrisa refleja el paso de las horas negras
tu mirada la más amarga desesperación
hoy para siempre quiero que olvides tus pasadas penas
y que tan sólo tenga horas serenas tu corazón

Quisiera ser la golondrina que al amanecer
a tu ventana llega para ver a través del cristal
y despertarte muy dulcemente si aun estás dormida
a la alborada de una nueva vida llena de amor

Quisiera ser la golondrina que al amanecer
a tu ventana llega para ver a través del cristal
y despertarte muy dulcemente si aun estás dormida

En El Ultimo Trag

Tómate esta botella conmigo
en el último trago nos vamos
quiero ver a qué sabe tu olvido
sin poner en mis ojos tus manos
Esta noche no voy a rogarte
Esta noche te vas que de veras
que difà cil trata de olvidarte
y que sienta que ya no me quieras

Nada me han enseñado los años
siempre caigo en los mismos errores
otra vez a brindar con extraños
y a llorar por los mismos dolores

Tómate esta botella conmigo
en el último trago me dejas
esperamos que no haya testigos
por si acaso te diera vergüenza
Si algún dà a sin querer tropezamos
no te agaches ni me hables de frente
simplemente la mano nos damos
y después que murmure la gente

Tuesday, June 02, 2009

Monday, May 11, 2009

Religions and Politics in India During the 13Th-Century

ndia and Pakistan
Religions and Politics in India During the 13Th-Century
Khaliq Ahmad Nizami
http://www.fis-iran.org/noruz.htm
http://www.fis-iran.org/amuzegar.htm
Foundation for Iranian Studies
THE NORUZ LECTURE SERIES

A Short History of the Foundation for Iranian Studies' Noruz lecture series
Each year around Noruz the Foundation for Iranian Studies, in cooperation with The George Washington University, organizes a public lecture on Iran under the title of 'The Annual Noruz Lecture Series by a Distinguished Scholar of Iranian Studies.' Each lecture is meant as a statement of a new idea or the summation of the work of a scholar in his or her field of concentration. Past lecturers include Khaliq Ahmad Nizami of the Aligarh Muslim University (1992), Gilbert Lazard of l'Academie des inscriptions et belles lettres (1993), Ezzat Negahban of the University of Pennsylvania (1994), Roger Savory of the University of Toronto (1995), and Guitty Azarpay of the University of California, Berkeley (1996), Ehsan Yarshater of Columbia University (1997, Peter Chelkowski of the New York University (1998), Seyyed Hossein Nasr of the George Washington University (1999), Jahangir Amuzegar (2000), and Pierre Briant of Collège de France (2001).

The 2001 Lecture
The FIS 2001 Noruz lecturer was Professor Pierre Briant of Collège de France. Professor Briant’s lecture, “The History of the Achaemenid Empire Today: New Trends and New Perspectives,” was delivered on Friday, March 23, 2001 at the George Washington University, Funger Hall, 2201 G street, Washington, DC. The lecture was followed by a reception around the “haft seen” table.
Professor Briant discussed the most recent developments in the study of the Achaemenid period, particularly in the following four areas: new archeological findings, the development of iconographic studies, reinterpretation of known documents, and a reexamination of the statistical approach to imperial control. Briant’s work constitutes the cutting edge of the contemporary Achaemenid studies. To access Professor Briant’s web page on Achaemenid studies, click http://www.achemenet.com/
The 2000 Lecture
'Perspectives on Iran's Post-revolution Economy'
Dr. Jahangir Amuzegar, Author, Scholar, Statesman
Friday, March 24, 2000, 7pm - 8:30pm
Ballroom, Marvin Center
The George Washington University
800 21st Street, N.W., Washington, DC
Followed by a reception adjoining the Ballroom
The 1999 Lecture:
Tuesday, March 23, 1999
'The Traditions of Philosophy in Iran'
By: Seyyed Hossein Nasr
University Professor of Islamic Studies,
George Washington University
The 1998 Lecture
Monday March 23, 1998
'Searching for Turandokht: From Nezami to Puccini'
Professor Peter Chelkowski
New York University
The 1997 Lecture
Tuesday, March 25, 1997
'In Search of the Secret of Survival: Reflections on the Khurasanian Cultural Resurgence'
Professor Ehsan Yarshter
Columbia University
To read Professor Yarshater's lecture click Reflections on the Khorassanian Cultural Resurgence
The 1996 Lecture
Monday, March 25, 1996
“Iran and the Silk Road: Art and Trade along Asia’s Crossroads”
Professor Guitty Azarpay
University of California, Berkeley
The 1995 Lecture
Thursday, March 16, 1995
“Is there an Ultimate Use for Historians? Reflections on Safavid History and Historiography”
Professor Roger Savory
Emeritus, University of Toronto
To read Professor Savory's lecture click Is There an Ultimate Use for Historians?
The 1994 Lecture
Wednesday, March 30, 1994
“Zaghe, Haft Tepe, and Marlik Excavations and Their Bearing on the Archeology of Iran”
Professor Ezat O. Negahban
University of Pennsylvania
The 1993 Lecture
Wednesday, March 17, 1993
“The Origins of Literary Persian”
Professor Gilbert Lazard
Academie des Inscriptions et Belles Lettres
Institut de France
1992 Lecture
Wednesday, March 25, 1992
“Persian Influence on the Development of Literary and Sufi Traditions in South Asia”
Professor Khaliq Ahmad Nizami
The Aligarh Muslim University



http://www.unesco.org/culture/aic/html_eng/volume5.htm

http://www.iuo.it/DIDATTICA/facolta/s_islamici/Guida-00-01/SSI-00-01.htm

Friday, May 08, 2009

Friday, May 01, 2009

the economic law of motion in modern societies

http://netx.u-paris10.fr/actuelmarx/economarx/refe1205.htm

schumpter marx

association suisse hist econ et soc

http://www.hist-ecosoc.ch/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=48&Itemid=66&lang=fr

tanner

http://www.collegium.ethz.ch/en/who-is-who/fellows/tanner.html

tanner pakistan seco

http://www.seco-cooperation.admin.ch/aktuell/highlights/00648/index.html?lang=fr

ass financial history

http://www.finanzgeschichte.ch/abstracts_english.htm

ass financial history

http://www.finanzgeschichte.ch/abstracts_english.htm

swiss banking secrecy

http://www.swissbanking.org/en/vogler-definitiv-deutsch.pdf

stein rokkan

http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Stein_Rokkan

http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cleavage_(politics)

http://www.decitre.fr/livres/Structures-de-clivages-systemes-de-partis-et-alignement-des-electeurs-une-introduction.aspx/9782800414270

stein rokkan

http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Stein_Rokkan

anaconda plan

http://www.aina.org/news/20090428171628.htm

Wednesday, April 29, 2009

The Roman predicament Par Harold James

The Roman predicament Par Harold James

The Nazi Dictatorship and the Deutsche Bank Par Harold James

harold james books



De l'indulgence vigilante à la saine gestion: l'évolution de la ...‎
de Harold James
Aucun aperçu disponible - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque

Les Nouvelles universités au Royaume-Uni / par H. J. Perkin‎
de Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Perkin, Harold James - 1969 - 283 pages
Aucun aperçu disponible - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque

The Third Reich: the essential readings‎
de Christian Leitz, Harold James - 1999 - 307 pages
This book presents a unique collection of some of the most influential recent writing on vital aspects of Nazi Germany.
Aperçu limité - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque

The Deutsche Bank and the Nazi economic war against the Jews: the ...‎
de Harold James - 2001 - 268 pages
James' unparalleled access and unusual perspective distinguishes this work as the only book to examine one company's involvement in the economic...
Aperçu limité - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque

International financial history in the twentieth century: system and anarchy‎
de Marc Flandreau, Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich, Harold James - 2003 - 278 pages
History of the international financial system in terms of the current globalization debate.
Aperçu limité - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque - Plus d’éditions

Family capitalism: Wendels, Haniels, Falcks, and the continental European model‎
de Harold James - 2006 - 434 pages
In Family Capitalism, James tells how "iron masters" of a classical industrial cast were succeeded by new generations who wanted to shift to...
Aperçu limité - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque - Plus d’éditions

The End of Globalization: Lessons from the Great Depression‎
de Harold James - 2002 - 260 pages
In this book, however, Harold James provides a sobering historical perspective, exploring the circumstances in which the globally integrated world of an...
Aperçu limité - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque

When the Wall came down: reactions to German unification‎
de Harold James, Marla Stone - 1992 - 351 pages
Affichage d'extraits - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque - Plus d’éditions

The German slump: politics and economics, 1924-1936‎
de Harold James - 1986 - 469 pages
This is the first survey of the German "slump" in English and the first in any language since important archives became available.
Affichage d'extraits - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque - Plus d’éditions

The Roman predicament: how the rules of international order create the ...‎
de Harold James - 2006 - 166 pages
So argues economic historian Harold James in this masterful work of intellectual history.
Aperçu limité - À propos de ce livre - Ajouter à ma bibliothèque

imf history

The IMF and the Force of History: Ten Events and Ten Ideas that Have Shaped the Institution

Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (IMF) (Paperback)

G20: A positive focus on the IMF, harold james
The summit was right to emphasise the role of the IMF, but countries dependent on the financial sector will still suffer


harold james

Let the IMF manage foreign reserves

subsidiarité

luhman


anarchie libertaire

subsidiarité etat

subsidiarité de l'etat, theorie, luhman

etat regulateur

cattacin subsidiarité luhman

les décisions sont prises " le plus près possible des citoyens, conformément au principe de subsidiarité ".
Le principe de la subsidiarité : il faut que l'État n'intervienne pas dans des affaires que l'individu ou la famille peuvent régler eux-mêmes


Sunday, April 19, 2009

daivd landes

http://unjobs.org/authors/david-s.-landes
http://books.google.ch/books?id=axrD2M9dBE8C&dq=landes+unbound+prometheus+technology&printsec=frontcover&source=bn&hl=fr&ei=H5PrSe-LHoOFsAa1nYWQBw&sa=X&oi=book_result&ct=result&resnum=4#PPP11,M1¨
http://eh.net/bookreviews/library/hohenberg
http://books.google.ch/books?id=WWztFfsA-QEC&pg=PA121&lpg=PA121&dq=David+S.+Landes+marxism++technology&source=bl&ots=aDhgJNZflN&sig=CeaW8uHKawODCbMRKK3zd3bxsqc&hl=fr&ei=2ZTrSdC8A8Sy_AbN4ODiAw&sa=X&oi=book_result&ct=result&resnum=1#PPA128,M1

http://www.nytimes.com/2006/10/29/books/review/Morris.t.html?ex=1319778000&en=5271b065c7098c36&ei=5090&partner=rssuserland&emc=rss

http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/53817/barry-eichengreen/geography-as-destiny-a-brief-history-of-economic-growth

http://www.wikiberal.org/wiki/Les_origines_de_l'Industrialisation


http://books.google.ch/books?id=axrD2M9dBE8C&dq=David+S.+Landes++unbound+prometheus+review&printsec=frontcover&source=bn&hl=fr&ei=85XrSYzwENaNsAaW0OWGBw&sa=X&oi=book_result&ct=result&resnum=4

Béatrice VEYRASSAT

http://books.google.ch/books?id=z4V3hy7ITrUC&pg=PA188&lpg=PA188&dq=beatrice+veyrassat&source=bl&ots=kKuw7xlUOS&sig=NEGHPFnl4RTja1awAzvWF0U8_YA&hl=de&ei=AfLqSfDEComB_Ab9kPT2Aw&sa=X&oi=book_result&ct=result&resnum=9#PPA173,M1
http://library.fes.de/jportal/receive/jportal_jparticle_00011452
h

Friday, April 17, 2009

1870s europe

http://www.sussex.ac.uk/polces/documents/r9001_r9002_.pdf
http://qed.econ.queensu.ca/pub/faculty/greena/econ231/handout.html
http://www.uio.no/studier/emner/hf/iakh/HIS2311/h03/pensumliste.xml

Tuesday, April 14, 2009

swiss banking

http://letemps.ch/Page/Uuid/723ecab4-2872-11de-91b6-01927b32cd2b/Le_prestige_du_Swiss_Banking_vient_de_ce_quil_opère_en_Suisse


OPINION Mardi14 avril 2009

Le prestige du Swiss Banking vient de ce qu’il opère en Suisse
PAR ROBERT U. VOGLER
, historien, ancien archiviste de la BNS, estime que la place financière suisse garde des avantages, le secret bancaire n’en étant qu’un parmi d’autres
Ni avant, ni après la Seconde Guerre mondiale les banques n’ont développé leurs affaires grâce au secret bancaire. Au contraire, de nombreuses banques ont dû lutter pour leur survie. A l’exemple de la Banque Populaire Suisse (BPS), qui a été sauvée dans les années 1930 par un apport de l’Etat dans son capital à hauteur de 100 millions de francs (un quart du budget de la Confédération de l’époque), assorti d’un siège gouvernemental au conseil d’administration. Cette lutte des établissements suisses pour leur survie a duré jusqu’à ce que les activités de gestion de fortune se portent vraiment bien, à la fin des années 1960. Mais le secret bancaire n’a jamais été vendu activement à l’étranger en tant qu’avantage concurrentiel. Ce n’était pas nécessaire car la Suisse pouvait faire valoir d’autres avantages, qui la rendaient attrayante pour les étrangers souhaitant déposer leurs avoirs dans ses banques.
La place financière et l’économie vantaient ces avantages comme un tout. En faisaient partie la stabilité politique et la sécurité du droit, comparées par exemple à la France qui de 1945 à la fin des années 1980 a nationalisé et reprivatisé ses banques par deux fois.
L’économie suisse a prospéré avec une inflation nettement moins élevée qu’à l’étranger. En outre, sa monnaie s’est imposée durant des décennies comme l’une des plus solides du monde. A l’époque de la Guerre froide, des crises pétrolières et de la dégradation de la valeur des devises dans de nombreux pays, la stabilité, voire la progression, de la monnaie était réjouissante pour les Suisses comme pour les étrangers. La Suisse n’ayant jamais connu de restrictions d’entrée ou de sortie des devises, le franc a été entièrement convertible en tout temps. Dans une modeste mesure, ces avantages politiques et économiques clairs ont été créés par la Suisse même, mais bien plus encore par ces circonstances défavorables, et souvent changeantes, dans les autres pays.
Dans le secteur de la gestion de fortune, les principaux clients des banques privées et cantonales, ainsi que des grandes banques, ont été depuis toujours des Français, des Italiens et des Allemands, et dans une moindre mesure des Américains. Les clients n’ont pas été les seuls à profiter de ces avantages. Grâce à une devise forte et à des taux d’intérêt bas, la place économique suisse a également profité de conditions financières avantageuses. Parmi les principaux bénéficiaires se trouvaient aussi la Confédération, les cantons et les communes, par le truchement des rentrées fiscales. Ces sommes ont été réinvesties principalement à l’étranger. Ce qui signifie que ces mêmes pays qui reprochent à la Suisse de s’enrichir grâce à la fraude et à la sous traction fiscale en ont tiré profit à leur tour.
Les attaques contre le secret bancaire helvétique font partie d’une longue tradition. Juste après la guerre, la place financière suisse et ses banques ont été régulièrement la cible des procureurs et des autorités américains. Sans oublier les (souvent) fausses déclarations dans les médias du monde entier, annonçant que tous les dictateurs et despotes auraient déposé des millions, voire des milliards, dans les banques suisses.
Le secret bancaire suisse s’est «fabriqué» une aura douteuse grâce aux romans de gare et aux films hollywoodiens de série B. Malgré une législation exemplaire et de nombreuses prescriptions en matière de blanchiment d’argent, cette image n’a pu être effacée aux yeux du monde.
Depuis quelques années, l’amélioration de la stabilité politique et économique dans de nombreux pays européens et dans d’autres régions du monde réduit ces avantages. Le secret bancaire reste important, mais n’est plus qu’un facteur parmi d’autres dans la concurrence que se livrent les places financières. Cependant sa valeur ne faiblit pas, si l’on en croit l’évolution que l’on observe en Allemagne notamment. L’intrusion des autorités fiscales directement dans les avoirs déposés dans les banques par les citoyens, les soi-disant «clients transparents», ne devrait bientôt plus avoir de légitimité. Par la force des choses, une certaine «confidentialité» deviendra indispensable si nous ne voulons pas déraper vers un Etat totalement policier. Le secret bancaire retrouvera bientôt toute sa signification.
Ce que la gauche et les ONG n’ont jamais réussi à obtenir semble désormais arriver du fait d’un mauvais modèle d’affaires dans la banque privée et du comportement malhonnête de collaborateurs d’une grande banque suisse. Le secret bancaire devrait aussi survivre à cette tempête.
Deux choses sont à changer: la différenciation entre fraude et évasion fiscales, peu compréhensible pour de nombreux Suisses, doit être définitivement supprimée. Il s’agit d’un seul et même délit, punissable par des amendes plus ou moins élevées, des rappels d’impôts et, dans les cas les plus graves, par de la prison. Deuxièmement, le «onshore banking» d’instituts suisses dans des pays étrangers, en particulier aux Etats-Unis, doit être considéré comme un modèle d’affaires erroné. Le «Swiss Banking» ne peut avoir du succès qu’en Suisse. Personne ne veut d’une Swatch faite en Chine ou d’une Rolex à Taïwan. De telles montres perdraient le label «Swiss Made».
En aucun cas, l’échange automatique d’informations ou les «fishing expeditions» menées par des autorités étrangères ne devraient être autorisés. Les politiciens et les banques doivent s’y opposer avec la plus grande fermeté, car les autres marchés financiers sauront profiter avec brutalité de la faiblesse de la Suisse. Mais si nous faisons bien notre travail, nous ressortirons renforcés de cette crise, les valeurs traditionnelles des banques suisses seront de nouveau opérantes et amèneront un nouvel élan, pour le bien de tous les citoyens.
*Auteur d’une étude sur le secret bancaire (www.swissbanking.ch).

Sunday, April 12, 2009

Vladimir Vysotskiy - Wir Drehen Die Erde

Track List:



1. Lyrisches Lied

2. Die Bergsteigerin

3. Moskau - Odessa

4. Haus Aus Kristall

5. Null Sieben

6. Die Giraffe

7. Kied Von Der Seelenwanderung

8. Schwarzes Gold

9. Kalte Gegenden, Kalte Gegenden

10. Es Ist Noch Nicht Abend

11. Weisser Walzer

12. Lied Vom Freund

13. Wir Drehen Die Erde

14. Alarmtrommeln - Über Die Neue Zeit

15. Lied Von Der Erde

16. Er Kam Nicht Aus Der Schlacht Zurück

17. Morgengymnastik

18. Abschied Von Den Bergen

19. Erschießung des Echos in Den Bergen

20. Die Söhne Ziehen in Den Kampf

21. Hinauf

22. Im Finstern

Yuri Golubev Yuri Golubev

Yuri Golubev
Co-founder of Yukos

Wednesday, April 08, 2009

ec his cursus

http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH417.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH412.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH464.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH487.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH475.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH463.htm

ec his cursus

http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH417.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH412.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH464.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH487.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH475.htm
http://www.lse.ac.uk/resources/calendar2008-2009/courseGuides/EH/2008_EH463.htm

Sunday, April 05, 2009

glashuette

http://www.glashuette.com/index.php?id=51

Mikhail Shishkin

http://academia-rossica.org/en/literature/russian-literature-week-2009/writers2/mikhail-shishkin
http://www.russiatoday.com/Art_and_Fun/2007-12-04/Italians_honour_contemporary_Russian_author.html
http://209.85.129.132/search?q=cache:RDQnLxfAca4J:www.ccsparis.com/archives/%3Fnav%3Dprogrammation%26menu%3D4+French+'La+Suisse+russe',+Fayard,+Paris,+2007.&cd=3&hl=de&ct=clnk&gl=ch
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Mikhail_Shishkin

Friday, March 27, 2009

yeoman american early republic

The Market Revolution: Jacksonian America, 1815-1846 (Paperback)

http://www.amazon.com/George-Clinton-Yeoman-Politician-Republic/dp/0945612184

http://muse.jhu.edu/login?uri=/journals/journal_of_the_early_republic/v029/29.1.sarson.html$

yeoman small indipendent farmers in the global and the local

second industrial divide

http://www.questia.com/googleScholar.qst?docId=5001271110

yeoman prussia

Sabel, Charles F.
Zeitlin, Jonathan.
Neither Modularity nor Relational Contracting: Inter-Firm Collaboration in the New Economy
Enterprise & Society - Volume 5, Number 3, September 2004, pp. 388-403


J. zeitlin , ch sabel , world of possibilities


JSTOR: The Second Industrial Divide - [ Traduire cette page ]
Charles Sabel, the younger of the two, is the author of Work and Politics: ... So Piore and Sabel conclude: "It is the ideal of yeoman democracy, we think, ...
links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0048-7511(198512)13%3A4%3C612%3ATSID%3E2.0.CO%3B2-I -

Friday, March 20, 2009

instituional change sufficient condition to eco growth?

new institutional economics and development

Distributional coalitions, the industrial revolution, and the origins of economic growth in Britain.


by Mokyr, Joel^Nye, John V.C.
Southern Economic Journal • July, 2007 • Symposium
1. Introduction

Structure and Change (1981), the recent work of Douglass North and his students, has made the study of institutions fashionable again in economic history. Mancur Olson's Rise and Decline (1982), which appeared only a year after North's Structure and Change, showed that he too was quite persuaded that institutions held the key to understanding why Britain took the leadership in the 18th century to become the first industrial nation. North focused on securing property rights from the threat of the monarchy. Olson regarded rent-seeking through distributional coalitions as critical to economic development and especially decline. He saw society as a constant struggle between creative and productive agents, whose hard work would help an economy enrich itself, and organized groups of lobbyists, special interests, brigands, and tax collectors, whose rent-seeking activity reduced the overall size of the pie and could well turn economic growth into stagnation and even regression. The difference between the two is important: For North, security and constraints on the executive were paramount. For Olson, the nature and origins of property rights were just as important. Almost a decade before North and Weingast's (1989) influential paper, which squarely identified the institutional breakthroughs in Britain with the Glorious Revolution of 1688 and its aftermath, Olson (1982, pp. 78-83, 128) already pointed to the Glorious Revolution as a watershed. These events of 1688-1689 and the preceding Civil Wars, Olson argued, created a stable and strong nationwide government that made Britain into an integrated and large jurisdictional unit, thus weakening most distributional coalitions.

In light of the growing interests in institutions as a central element in explaining economic growth (Greif 2006; North 2006), the question of how institutions help account for the British Industrial Revolution must be re-examined. Olson (1982, p. 78) thought that the British practically "invented modern economic growth" during their Industrial Revolution. Although the actual spurt in per capita income occurred after and not during the Industrial Revolution, many of the critical changes that laid the foundations for the Great Divergence took place in the years of the classical period that T. S. Ashton associated with it (1760-1830). The difficult question is to what extent institutional changes were necessary for this transformation to occur. The main impetus, surely, came from technology. Along a broad frontier, technological changes transformed the way production took place in textiles, power technology, materials, and transport. Although the "modern sector" still composed a relatively modest part of the economy in 1830, it was growing rapidly and was soon to subsume the bulk of the economy.

Traditionally, the role that institutions have played in this event has figured heavily in the literature on the topic. Much of their effect has been through their direct encouragement of technological progress (through the British patent system, for instance) or through the importance of secure property rights, enforceable contracts, and constraints on the powers of the executive. Recent work has suggested that the importance of intellectual property rights or other kinds of incentive systems in encouraging innovation has been overrated, however, and secure property rights in and of themselves will not necessarily encourage innovation (Boldrin and Levine 2005). Rather, as Olson pointed out quite correctly, the security of property rights could have ambiguous effects. A bad property right, such as a privilege or sinecure that entitled a successful pressure group to some form of government subsidy or protection or encroached on the incentives of another group, could be damaging to economic development even if it was perfectly secure and well-defined. In what follows, we will present what is essentially an Olsonian model and will place the Industrial Revolution in the context of the slow decline of rent-seeking distributional coalitions. However, it will turn out to be a more complex story than the simple good-institutions-lead-to-growth story.

It is possible to disagree with some of the details in Olson's analysis, but not with his overall vision. The answers to the questions "why Britain?" and "why the 18th century?" must have two separate, if interrelated, components. First, there is a technological component that explains the advantages that British inventors had over others and that British entrepreneurs had in implementing inventions made elsewhere (Mokyr 2002). Second, there was an institutional advantage that ensured that incentives for talented and resourceful individuals, able to take advantage of the opportunities that technology provided, were properly set up. In other words, there had to be an environment in which opportunistic behavior by Olsonian "bandits" would not create obstacles and hindrances high enough to suppress the technological potential that 18th century Britain developed. The British created a powerful and stable state that simultaneously saw an expansion in the power, wealth, and stability of the central government while encouraging an economic transformation that gradually allowed both industrial technology and liberal commerce to flourish and break out of their mercantilist straitjacket.

What was behind institutional change? Was ideology an autonomous factor in these changes, or were the basic economic realities on the ground decisive here? Following Keynes' famous argument in The General Theory that ideas were infinitely more important than vested interests in affecting economic outcomes, we may well ask to what extent the institutional changes in 18th century Britain were driven by ideological rather than "real" factors. Economists typically feel that economic realities on the ground determine ideology and beliefs, not the other way around. Adam Smith claimed that the self-interest of merchants in an enlarged national and international commerce tore down the old, local feudal restrictions and in doing so brought prosperity to town and country both, and "commerce and manufactures gradually introduced order and good government and with them the liberty and security of individuals" (1776, Book 3, ch. IV; p. 433 in the Cannan edition). (1) For them, then, the causality ran from economic developments to changes in institutions. But, we shall argue, things were more complex than that.

2. Political Power and Rent-Seeking in 18th Century Britain

What were the details of the transition whereby further expansion of the British state contributed to improved order and commerce without using the power of the State to deform or even to crush free exchange? In this regard, the paper by North and Weingast (1989), emphasizing how important it was that the Crown and Parliament accept complementary roles that saw each check the power of the other while building the foundation of a stable and nonarbitrary state, has served as a benchmark for all economic interpretations of 18th century political economy. But the details of how this compromise managed to produce the conditions for an economic revolution without disenfranchising the stakeholders in the traditionalist economy have never been made clear.

At the end of the day, the problem for 18th century Britain, as it is for today's developing economies, was that there was much to be gained by many incumbents from maintaining "obsolete" economic arrangements. Because rent-seeking and efforts to create exclusions and other privileges exploiting existing inefficiencies and creating new ones were so pervasive and so longstanding, blocking coalitions existed that stood to lose much from any set of reforms, no matter how productive. Investments that exploited existing inefficiencies were not easily abandoned if it was not possible to persuade the vested interests that they could benefit from large-scale transformative changes. Though the total gains to the winners--society as a whole might well overwhelm the costs to the losers, the losers will choose to stand in the way of changes if they are not properly compensated. Mancur Olson argued in The Rise and Decline of Nations (1982) that the most successful reforms have often come in moments of crisis when organized vested interests are broken or destabilized or when outside forces can impose new rules without excessive concern for the losses of the entrenched powers. Often the critical factors that allowed the overthrow of existing power coalitions blocking reform were exogenous shocks that led to the breakdown of existing power coalitions and a reordering of priorities. We will show that British institutional developments in the age of the Industrial Revolution demonstrate that such shocks were neither necessary nor sufficient conditions for successful change.

For the Industrial Revolution to be successful, Britain had to overcome the problem of incumbent landed powers that drew their political, social, and economic strength from the existing blend of feudal customs and traditional arrangements. For example, improving landlords and entrepreneurial farmers had opportunities to innovate in agriculture and to rearrange property rights through enclosures. These opportunities implied, in turn, that those who where least successful in making such experiments should abandon agriculture at considerable cost. Yet the losers in the process were unable to stop it using either legal or extralegal means. After 1750, the state had chosen sides. Although property rights remained one of the central mantras of Parliamentary rules, many of the activities of the 18th century British State "removed, reallocated, and in short, invaded property" (Langford 1991, p. 146). Property required regulation and enforcement, and in the 18th century, decisions were made increasingly on the basis of national interests.

Outside farming, regulation and transport costs had long protected a system of local monopolies and mercantile niches. The small merchants and producers who had traditionally operated under the conditions of a fragmented market characterized by monopolistic competition had to be persuaded--or forced--to make the switch to a more integrated and efficient national market. As many have noted, "most important was that Britain had a truly national market, the integration of which was progressing, thanks to the absence of internal customs and tolls, to internal transport movements, ... and to the impetus of the enormous and fast-growing city of London" (Crouzet 2001, p. 111). (2)

Market integration, paired with political centralization, was central to the process of economic development. The creation of an integrated market, often credited with British economic progress, was in large part the outcome of a political process. The regional fragmentation of pre-modern economies usually had not meant political competition, but rather constituted a balkanized system of local monopolies that impeded the workings of the national economy, protecting niches of inefficiency from competition. (3) These niches preserved local custom and diversity but also encouraged a diffuse network of small-scale mediocrity at the margins of agriculture, artisanal production, and commerce. It is thus a matter of great historical significance that the British authorities in the 18th century did not overly interfere with free domestic trade. It took a mere century or so for the conditions to emerge that destroyed the sources of many locational rents. In the integrated economy, new concentrations of production emerged that undermined the many small, local quasi-monopolies that were the lumpy residue of a world of high transactions costs and protected market exchange. Above all, there had to be a way to make room for a rising merchant and industrialist class as they asserted their power in the political sphere and posed an increasing threat to the existing political class.

The success of the British experiment was the result of the emergence of a progressive oligarchic regime that divided the surpluses generated by the new economy between the large landholders and the newly rising businessmen, and that tied both groups to a centralized government structure that promoted uniform rules and regulations at the expense of inefficient relics of an economic ancient regime. Wealth--inherited or earned--remained the source of political power, but as its base broadened, its political objectives shifted. Some of this transformation can be gleaned by considering how politics changed over the period from the Glorious Revolution in the late 17th century to the first decades of Walpole's ministership in the early 1700s. As Plumb's work on British elections indicates, political stability came through the rise of a two-party system that favored large-scale campaign funding and competitive elections often requiring a regional, or even national, level of influence. (4) The grand coalition between big landowners and the emerging urban-commercial class (with particular prominence of the financial interests) as represented by the dominant Whig party became the central feature of this polity, but the Industrial Revolution that it created would be its eventual downfall.

With the creation of a more centralized administrative structure and a more powerful military apparatus, the state needed greater revenues. These were most forthcoming from a rising national commerce that was liberated (or "freed up") but also subject to taxation. This policy can be contrasted with one that just tried to extract more revenues from the landed classes. The most powerful commercial interests were co-opted into this bargain by a mercantilist policy that placed the military power of the state at the service of their colonial interests. The resulting alliance of Big Land and Big Commerce helped to undermine smaller country gentlemen (mostly associated with the Tory party) who might otherwise have stood in the way of reform. Conversely, the owners of large estates who had learned to profit from economic integration, industrialization, and political oligarchy acquired a stake in further commercialization. This coalition in turn--centered as it was on Parliament served as a counterpoint and check on any attempts by the King and Court to regain supremacy.

Of course, there were losers from this transformation, both in a relative and in an absolute sense. Small-scale farmers (yeomen and cottagers) and the workers in the large domestic industry, as well as increasing numbers of independent artisans, found themselves at the losing end of this process. Local merchants and niche producers, who were accustomed to making a modest but secure living in an economy of fragmented production, increasingly faced competition at a national level and could no longer keep up or count on either explicit government protection or the natural shield of high transportation costs. (5) This allowed for improved productivity, increasing quality standardization, and, by reducing uncertainty, the realization of certain economies of scale (Szostak 1991). These developments inevitably occurred at the expense of many small merchants who now found themselves subject to the discipline of a competitive national market, as outsiders began to encroach on their once-safe niches.

Throughout the 18th century, transportation costs kept declining through a combination of better roads, improved carriages and transport organization, canals, and improved coastal shipping. Unlike most of its 18th century competitors, Britain had no internal tariffs, tolls, or other artificial encumbrances to internal trade, excepting the tolls charged on for-profit turnpikes and canals. British Parliament did not directly engage in raising funds for transport infrastructure, but it played an important passive role by approving private bills for turnpike trusts and canals (Bogart 2005). The net result was a growing integrated national economy in which the monopolistic competition that had kept local rents at high levels was gradually eroded. (6)

3. Parliament, Power, and Institutional Change

What explains the adaptive efficiency of British institutions? Their agility was facilitated by the existence of a meta-institution that wrote the rules by which other institutions changed. This function was filled by Parliament. For a meta-institution to be effective, above all, it needs to have legitimacy; that is, even the losers will accept its verdicts, much like the United States Supreme Court. (7) To be sure, British Parliament in the 18th century was a corrupt institution by our standards. However, its venality may have been a form of efficient corruption. Politicians and legal changes for local and specific purposes were practically up for sale through what was known as "private bills." (8) Yet precisely for that reason, British institutions turned out to be adaptable and agile. During the entire period under discussion, British Parliament changed British laws and arrangements in accordance with what its members viewed as their interests and Britain's needs. The importance of the Glorious Revolution, then, was in leaving no doubt as to the supreme power of Parliament: The Bill of Rights and subsequent legislation eliminated the royal prerogative as a form of legislation, established Parliamentary oversight on government spending, and ensured that it met regularly and maintained control over the royal succession. In that sense, the Glorious Revolution was a watershed event, not so much because it laid the foundation of the successful system of public finance, which was to play a central role in the growing political power of Britain (Brewer 1988), but rather because it removed the contestability of rule-making from the British polity and established a body that was receptive to both changing needs and changing ideology.

It is no exaggeration to say that the activity of British Parliament, measured by the number of acts passed, increased by orders of magnitude after the Glorious Revolution. As Hoppit (1996) has shown, from 1688 to 1800 the sheer number of Parliamentary bills grew enormously. (9) The bulk of this legislation were local and specific acts, which applied to one particular project or estate, that enabled a local public good or changed a settlement and allowed the redeployment of land to more productive and remunerative purposes (Hoppit 1996, p. 131). There is no question that this legislation was a mechanism by which the richest and most powerful families of England manipulated the system to advance their interests. Local elites acquired access to the center, as Hoppit notes, and acts were responses to local needs and ad hoc initiatives of an individual or small group. Such local changes, however, depended more and more on the legitimacy of Parliament. There was no guarantee that establishing Parliament as "the place where absolute despotic power, which must in all governments reside somewhere, is entrusted," as Blackstone noted in 1765, was to become the key to economic progress. After all, the newly found power of Parliament could just as likely have been abused by special interest legislation in support of distributive coalitions.

In the decades following the Glorious Revolution, rent-seeking activity was indeed the norm. "Specific" legislation directed at a particular place or institution remained between two-thirds and three-quarters of all acts throughout the period 1688-1800. (10) Much of the 18th century legislation remained in Langford's words, "a great bog of uncoordinated lawmaking, ever expanding but always unplanned" (1991, p. 156). Yet at some point during the 18th century, a gradual change in the culture of legislation occurred. Special interests were still accommodated so long as they concerned statutory legislation supporting local public goods and appointed bodies that would carry out infrastructural investments. Purely redistributional actions, however, began losing their appeal. Many special interest groups' legislated privileges, monopolies, exclusions, limitations on labor mobility, occupational choice, and technological innovation found themselves on the defensive as the 18th century wore on and the ideas of the Enlightenment began to sink in. It was a very different Parliament in 1774 that tossed out the Calicot Act--a shameless piece of special interest legislation benefiting the wool and silk industry--from the one that had passed it in 1721.

Dan Bogart and Gary Richardson (2006) have a more recent, detailed study of Parliamentary Acts after the Glorious Revolution, showing a substantial increase in acts altering property rights and encouraging the provision of public goods. The numbers of such acts passed increased from 30 per year in the 1600s to 400 per year by the end of the 18th century. The acts were primarily of three types: estate, statutory authority, and enclosure acts. The first were important because they eliminated traditional restrictions on the use of private land and "authorized the improvement, sale, and leasing of land; and thus, enabled land to be shifted to higher value uses" (Bogart and Richardson 2006, p. 2). The statutory authorities allowed for the provision of greater public goods such as roads or bridges by private organizations, thus mitigating important collective action problems. And, as is well-known, the enclosure acts transformed the lands affected from collectively cultivated open fields to consolidated private lands.

Although there were losers as well as winners from these acts, they promoted a clear-cut shift to a more liberal, market economy. Parliament continued to redistribute income deep into the 19th century. However, instead of just serving the powerful and the well connected, a different pattern emerged. The legislation took place in an increasingly centralized fashion, in large part to placate powerful incumbents that could have blocked other forms of institutional change. It stands to reason that landowners realized the gains they could secure with improved communications and higher urban land values. In agriculture, the enclosure movement relying on Parliamentary Enclosure Bills represented the same kind of phenomenon. As Allen (1992) has shown, some of the increase in rents from enclosure came not from productivity gains, but from transfers from weaker stakeholders to the most successful landholders.

Hoppit (1996) tries to distinguish between supply and demand factors in the sharp increase in Parliamentary activity. The changes in 1688-1689 did not so much shift the supply curve to the right as much as rotated it to make it more elastic. When an increase in the demand for specific legislation took place, Parliamentary approval was in most areas forthcoming fairly quickly. In some areas, of course, this took a long time to work itself out; after 1720, it was difficult for companies to acquire joint-stock status. Special interest legislation could be used to block entry and create redistributive rents as readily as they could be used to liberalize markets and set up organizations that invested in overhead capital. Moreover, Rubinstein (1983) has called attention to the importance of rent-seeking in late 18th and early 19th century Britain in his work on "Old Corruption." By corruption, he meant both the Crown's patronage capacity to reward supporters and allies, as well as the persistence of sinecures and offices used purely as a means of enriching individuals rather than to serve a utilitarian role in administration (p. 57). (11) Rubinstein asked why such "pre-modern" arrangements persisted and even flourished until the 1830s or later, implicitly sensing that by the first third of the 19th century this kind of rent-seeking had become misplaced. His answer, that this was the "stagnant" persistence of a pre-modern, pre-rationalistic elite is unconvincing. It is more plausible that such "corruption" was the byproduct of the expansion of the state and the substitution of a national administrative system for the more localized feudal institutions. The expanded elements of the Old Corruption that characterized the late 18th century owed much of their existence to the State-creating and rent-making efforts of the Walpole Whigs of a previous century.

On the whole, however, as the 18th century proceeded, Parliament increasingly used its powers to make dents in the rent-seeking machinery of the ancient regime and make the economy more efficient and streamlined. Parliament reserved the right to revise and amend the rights it provided to individuals, and a growing number of acts amended, repealed, or renewed explicit legislation. Judges who were characterized by petty corruption and destructive political competition in the 17th century (Ekelund and Tollison 1997) were displaced by a system that favored an orderly and more centralized bureaucracy in which corruption was either focused or became subsumed in the general rent-seeking at the Parliamentary and not the retail level. (12) Parliament, rather than a venal institution that awarded the rights to the highest bidder, became the arbitrator of disputes between special or local interest groups.

It would thus be oversimplified to argue that rent-seeking went into decline in the late 18th century through a combination of business interest and changes in ideology influenced by Enlightenment philosophers and political economists. Rent-seeking coalitions saw to it that British goods would always be preferred to foreign goods and that everything should be done in the interest of the nation. The important part is that Parliament looked after national interests, whereas, as we argued above, much of pre-modern rent-seeking was localized. (13) By the late 18th century, Prime Minister William Pitt refused to meddle in local matters, which were "large areas of policy in which ministers and party politicians need not involve themselves" (Langford 1991, p. 205; and see Pitt 1808). The areas of the most intensive rent-seeking in the 18th century were part of a bargain struck between those who fed income to the excise authorities and a government that spared increases in land taxes in favor of taxing middle class consumption and restricting imports from abroad. The result was that domestic trade was freed in the 18th century at the expense of free international commerce (Nye 2007). This often meant making deals whereby Parliament actually had greater ability to extract rents from the national economy than it had previously.

It is not obvious from the standpoint of liberal ideology or competitive efficiency that Britain was better off in the decades after the Glorious Revolution. After all, the bulk of taxes in the 18th century were used to finance wars or pay interests on debts incurred during wartime. These wars did not materially benefit British society except insofar as they protected British citizens and merchants, both in Britain itself and its colonies, from potential raids. To attribute economic success to the blue-seas policy of the Hanoverians is to take a partial view of the process. (14) After all, these raids were often prompted by Britain's aggressive mercantilist policies. These mercantilist policies, to the extent that they benefited anyone, protected a narrow range of merchants, manufacturers, financiers, ship-owners, and planters and thus constituted redistribution from the tax-paying public to a small special interest group. There was a decline in the willingness of and need for the British government to engage in these activities after the American War of Independence, but the Wars of 1793-1815 resumed military spending and raised them to unprecedented levels.

Later 18th century policies were driven not only by interests and power, but also by a growing understanding that the free market made the people in power and the political and military apparatus that supported them better off. Time and again the government chose to promote legislation that solved collective action problems while refraining from too much micromanagement. Remarkably, the areas in which the state played a role in legislation seems broadly consistent with a market-enabling authority seeking to internalize externalities, solve coordination problems, and facilitate public works and investment in overhead capital. (15) The importance of these investments was in advancing the efficiency of markets and further reducing the enclaves of local rents. But the effects did not stop there. Alliances of landlords and merchants invested in mines, canals, lighthouses, harbors, land drainage, and roads even before railroads were an option. These projects produced opportunities for engineers and hardware manufacturers such as John Smeaton and Richard Trevithick to utilize their technical skills and create the new technologies that we think of as the Industrial Revolution. The state also recognized its responsibilities in setting standards such as weights and measures. (16)

Regulations that directly interfered with the workings of domestic trade and the marketplace and created rents for special interest groups seemed few and far between as the 18th century proceeded. Foreign trade was another matter: The Corn Laws and legislation prohibiting the export of machinery and emigration of skilled artisans remained on the books until deep into the 19th century. These were rent-seeking arrangements, to be sure, but very much at the national level. Nationalized rules made for easier government growth but also made it easier for a government to become visibly reformed, which occurred in the 19th century. The sharp rise in taxation through customs and excise that characterized the fiscal shifts in the 18th century can be seen as the "price" the state exacted for its new role as market facilitator, even if the new taxes were not always ideal and even if the taxes and customs were distorted to favor this or that interest group.

When did this process start? According to North and Weingast (1989), the locus classicus of changes in the British institutional structure remains despite the fact that some of their more detailed claims have come under criticism. Their story points to 1688-1689 as the turning point. They make two separate claims: (i) the need for the Crown to reach agreement with the legislator before authorizing taxation to match expenditure and (ii) the ability of the government to collect the revenues they wished successfully. After all, a unified state might impose a tax without having either the administrative capability or the coercive strength to collect. At the very least, there must be high enough compliance with a tax so that evasion does not nullify any rise in the official rates. With sufficient improvements in collection efficiency and the growth of a middle class whose consumption of excisable goods was expanding, tax rates did not need to rise for revenues to increase substantially in the 18th century. The rise of a wealthy and prosperous state overseeing an efficient fiscal administration in the 18th century made it possible for the liberal elites to design a more responsive, modern mechanism with which to implement more enlightened reforms and eliminate the last vestiges of mercantilism after 1820. Having established the benefits of an open national market and a rapidly expanding international commerce, the path was opened for the grand experiment of a liberal economy with minimal rent-seeking that eventually attained nearly complete free trade.

4. Taxes, Elites, and Economic Reforms

We need to better understand transitions in which critical elites allowed processes to unfold that ultimately destroyed some of their entrenched positions. In Britain, no violent revolution brought this about. A nation dominated by landed nobility acquiesced in the creation and encouragement of a system in which a new merchant class shifted the distribution of political power away from land and toward capital, commerce, and eventually labor. Production shifted from agriculture to industry and services, from local to national markets and then to international commerce. In the long run, this had the effect of undermining the traditional nobility's power and destroying the social system that supported them. In Britain, the elites were not forcibly eliminated. Instead, they were co-opted into an economic transformation when the immediate rewards offered them were sufficiently great that the long-term change that was to erode their political dominance was either invisible or seemed unimportant. Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2005, p. 461) pose the question starkly: Why did elites in Britain create a democracy, when in fact political power is the key to the distribution of income? Their answer is that repression was costly as well and that the threat of violent revolution gave the disenfranchised masses in Britain a de iure power that eventually forced the elite to hand over power. Elsewhere, in Eastern and Central Europe they maintain, the elites felt that this threat was weak and thus they could resist reform.

If political power meant the ability to generate rents, the British elite were squeezing as much income from their privileged positions as possible. The striking fact about the Industrial Revolution is that its main economic beneficiaries until the mid-19th century were the old landowning classes, who benefited from rising land values in strategic areas (including urban areas, coal mines, and water power sites). As a class, the landowners were able to maintain the Corn Laws to protect their agricultural rents. Since the late 17th century, the Corn Laws had actually provided a "bounty" (i.e., a subsidy) for grain exports, and although that bounty was abolished in 1815, a system of graduated tariffs attempted to protect landed interests. By the middle of the 19th century, even that was no longer politically viable. Until that time, the landed classes seem to have done well from the Industrial Revolution. (17) Equally important, the landlord class retained its political power deep into the industrial age, assuring that the new economic captains would commit to respect their economic interests. As Acemoglu and Robinson (2000) suggest, institutional changes that leave much of the political structure intact have a better chance to succeed.

One indicator of how the British landowning class was co-opted to join those that it could not beat can be seen in the structure and magnitude of British tax receipts. From the Glorious Revolution through the end of the 18th century, total government income rose at a rate nearly five times faster than gross domestic product growth. Most of the changed revenue came in the form of increased excises and customs receipts. Yet revenues from land taxes remained virtually unchanged for most of the 18th century (O'Brien and Hunt 1993). The costs of a powerful military and the funds that had to be extracted from the nation during the early years of the Industrial Revolution fell only minimally on the landed nobility, who saw their total direct contribution to the state remain more or less steady, whereas the consuming middle classes paid more and more in excise taxes and tariffs.

Thus, the British elite did not effectively impede the growing commerce in the 18th century, nor did it impose insuperable obstacles to the spread of industry throughout Britain. They could not have anticipated that these changes in technology and production would not just revolutionize British production in only a few industries but would eventually invert the entire relationship between town and country. It is also clear, however, that many of the elite had the presence of mind to jump on the bandwagon of a rapidly changing economy. By 1700, Britain was already unusual because of its high degree of urbanization and the relatively small share of the economy devoted to agriculture (second only to the United Provinces, where the landed classes had already ceded effective power to the commercial oligarchy), particularly compared with its continental rivals.

5. Parliament: From Individual Influence to the Rise of Party Loyalty

In the 18th century, political control was increasingly centralized in London and Parliament and was supported by the creation of a centralized civil service, especially with regard to taxation. The number of full-time employees in the fiscal bureaucracy grew from 2524 in 1690 to 8292 in 1782-1783 (Brewer 1988, p. 66)--still a small number by modern standards, but a respectable growth by the standards of the time. As we argued above, in the medium run, centralization led to the shift in rent-seeking activities from a fragmented but highly local provincial structure to a national system in which local patronage operated through members of Parliament (MPs). In the long run, this very same system allowed for a shift from locally directed patronage to distributional struggles that were more broadly focused on national concerns. In other words, the long-term institutional transformation of Britain between the Glorious Revolution and the 1867 Reform Act went through distinct stages. First a change of locus occurred, then, as a new ideology took root and a new power structure emerged, rent-seeking itself was put on the defensive.

This view is consistent with the historical literature in political science on changing voter patterns in Britain. As argued in the classic work of Gary Cox (1986), electoral influence shifted from being a means of exercising local control through regulation and patronage to serve as a unifying feature of party campaigns that turned on national issues rather than local favoritism. This shift was the culmination of a political transition many decades in the making. Cox argued that this shift--the final stage of which took place in the mid to late 1800s--could be observed by the change in split voting in double-member districts that occurred throughout the century. Whereas earlier, voters in such districts tended to favor candidates from each of the major parties to preserve favors regardless of party success, by the mid 1800s, voters were more likely to focus their voting in response to tighter party discipline that nationalized the campaigns. (18)

This type of political wheeling and dealing was made possible by the close connection between issues of licensing and taxation with the centralized administration of the state. As a result of the shift of political power to Parliament in the 18th century, local influence had to be channeled through local representatives in London. This made individual MPs quite powerful and was a special concern in districts in which either of the major parties might win the election. In these cases, Cox claims that voters often acknowledged both the importance of patronage and the risks of displeasing the wrong group, splitting votes between parties to succeed in "giving offence to neither party" (Cox 1986, p. 212).

Cox's thesis, which is now the mainstream of political thinking, was that the decline in split voting matched the disappearance in this sort of electoral influence. This is because British policy changed to remove many forms of legislation that permitted the rent-seeking in the first place. Cox's view is that legislators' influence was most critical in the provision of divisible benefits to constituents, such as tariff bills, civil service patronage, and local improvement bills (Cox 1986, p. 209). But with the rise of free trade, the elimination of patronage in the civil service, and nondiscretionary/"laissez-faire" rules for the allocation of public goods, individual MPs simply had little to offer local constituencies. (19)

As local discretion waned, voters began to care about the actions of parties, not individuals. This in turn spurred 19th century parties to nationalize the issues and impose party discipline, leading to more coherent positions. This thesis fits well with our claim that the creation of a transparent electoral system did not initially reduce rent-seeking in the 18th century. In creating systematic rules on the basis of a national administrative machinery, however, the state established the conditions for changes that would eventually undermine rent-seeking itself. The initial centralization of control allowed for ample rent-seeking throughout the 18th century. But that selfsame system was easily changed as reforms stamped out many of the legislative prerogatives that provided for regulatory and bureaucratic redistribution. In effect, the system that favored pork-barrel politics in the Walpole era could not be credibly maintained as the ideological winds in the late 18th century shifted to favor a more liberal, hands-off regulatory order. By the middle of the 19th century, in any case, the old patronage system, after a prolonged decline, was finally on the way out. Particularly striking was the shift in the rules regarding "private" bills governing such things as turnpikes and local roads and later the construction of canals and railroads, regulation of sanitation, and eventually the provision of other public goods such as utilities and local transportation. (20) This effectively destroyed the last remnants of individual patronage. The individual MP could no longer offer his direct services to the district by agreeing to oversee the passage of individual bills. The system of individually sponsored private bills that had been the backbone of the rent-sharing arrangements that the State had created jointly with provincial elites was thus dismantled. The procedural changes in the 19th century effectively changed the rules and simply disenfranchised MPs as patrons en masse. The result was a switch to party discipline and an organizational restructuring whereby the influence that MPs could offer was more along the lines of trying to influence national party policy since they could no longer offer particularized benefits. What were the ideological origins of this transformation?

Mercantilism and the Liberal Enlightenment (21)

Much of the literature regarding institutional change focuses on economic interests and the political power necessary to ensure an income distribution favorable to one group or another and, hence, is focused on issues such as the ability of a group in society to commit to certain promises it makes to another group and the capacity of interest groups to overcome collective bargaining issues. Although such issues are unquestionably central, they leave little room for ideology. Yet the history of the European Enlightenment demonstrates North's argument that what people believed about the world in which they lived and the principles they thought governed their societies played an important role in shaping these institutions. It is true, as Acemoglu and Robinson (2000) and Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2005) state, that people have preferences over institutions because institutions imply a certain allocation of resources and distribution of income, but this is not the entire story. People also have a view of the way society ought to work, an awareness of what institutions make sense to them and what appeals to their concepts of fairness and logic. In the end, these beliefs help determine what kind of institutions are selected and survive. Beliefs, however, are not constant: People are open to learning, to persuasion, to new methods of understanding reality. Ideas compete in a market for ideas, in which intellectual innovators provide new products to a public of educated consumers (Mokyr 2007). The largest product "sold" in the 18th century was the Enlightenment.

By the start of the 18th century, the British state was still firmly wedded to Mercantilist principles. Although the exact meaning and significance of mercantilism as an ideology (the term "economic doctrine" seems anachronistic) is still a matter of serious debate, two themes have emerged from recent work. One is that mercantilism represented a coalition between rent-seeking interests and the national fiscus that was at the core of much economic policy in the 18th century and before. This theme was particularly emphasized by Ekelund and Tollison (1981, 1997). The other (e.g., O'Brien 2002; Ormrod 2003) is the belief that wealth and political/ military power were mutually indispensable and implied one another. Both of these ideologies were a manifestation of the underlying notion that the economic game, whether played internationally or locally, was zero-sum, in which the gains of one were inevitably the loss of the other. (22) From that assumption it followed that if one could exclude others from trade by forcible means, a gain would accrue to the nation as a whole, although this gain inevitably benefited some groups and not others. The legislation represented special interests, but it came under fire after 1760. (23)

In the second half of the 18th century, mercantilist doctrines faced increasing critique from influential thinkers. (24) It is an irony of British history that, after a false dawn between 1783 and 1793 when it seemed that these doctrines were definitely on the retreat, the French and Napoleonic Wars led to a serious setback and a revival of trade-reducing foreign policies. Indeed, it is a testimony to the strength of the rise of liberal ideas that they survived the reactionary policies of the war period at all.

A corollary of mercantilist principles was that British interests should always take precedence over foreign ones and that the military apparatus of the state should be deployed in the service of these interests. It was a world view uniquely suitable to support policies in the defense of special interests (Ekelund and Tollison 1981, 1997). Yet even in a mercantilist world, the importance of the interests of the nation as a whole and the need to provide for the common good cannot be dismissed altogether as a motive for public policy. Mercantilism was as much a doctrine of national-dynastic interests as it was a doctrine of economic defense or a response to feared aggressiveness of other nations in a Hobbesian world order. It advocated a positive balance of trade because it was believed that the flow of gold into a country would enable its rulers to hire mercenaries and build ships to defend the realm and protected special interests with a stake in the British colonies. Moreover, mercantilist writers were deeply concerned about employment and advocated what would be called in the 20th century a "beggar thy neighbour" policy, supporting exports and curtailing imports in the vain hope of creating "jobs." Most economists today would regard these policies as questionable, but they cannot all be dismissed as motivated by mere narrow-minded special interest. Although they were almost invariably based on a mercantilist zero-sum view of the world, they represented national and not local interests. Once enough policymakers changed their understanding of the nature of the economic game, it was easier to change course.

Whatever their exact source, the reforms that were introduced in Europe and North America between 1770 and 1830 significantly reduced the total amount of rent-seeking in the Western world. Olson's distributional coalitions reached a zenith in the two decades following 1850. Although the precise quantification of that phenomenon cannot be attempted here, there is little doubt that it took place. In Britain after 1760, legislation was passed that got rid of practically all residual monopolistic and exclusionary practices. Thus, the Statute of Artificers was abolished in 1814, the enumeration clauses (that forced British colonial goods to be shipped to third markets through Britain) in the Navigation Acts were repealed in 1822, the law prohibiting the emigration of artisans was repealed in 1824, the export prohibition on machinery was weakened in 1824 and repealed in 1843, and the Bubble Act was thrown out in 1825. (25) All in all, a great deal of special interest legislation was swept away. The rationalization of weights and measures, too, had this dimension. The proliferation of weights and measures was a traditional source of rents that seriously increased transaction costs (Alder 1995). Enlightenment ideology required the rationalization of economic transactions, and multiple standards increased uncertainty and transaction costs. (26)

Trade liberalization started in the 18th century after the American Revolution. The Eden treaty of 1786 with France was an important step forward. Many of Britain's leading figures after 1760 had become convinced free traders. The Eden treaty could have been the start of a new and enlightened age of free trade, had it not been for the setback of the French Revolution. Trade liberalization resumed in the early 1820s with William Huskisson, followed by abolition of the Corn Laws in 1846 and what remained of the ultra-mercantilist Navigation Acts in 1849, and culminated in the Cobden-Chevalier treaty of 1860. The way to the Free Trade Britain of legend, all the same, was not easy. Britain hesitated long and hard before it fully committed to free trade in the second half of the 19th century, reflecting the power of rent-seeking at the national level and the many difficulties and ambiguities in the enlightenment arguments for free trade. The gradual weakening of the farming sector's hold on political life after the Napoleonic wars meant a confrontation that ended with the repeal of the Corn Laws in the 1840s. Yet, as we now know, even the end of the Corn Laws did not immediately result in the full liberalization of trade (Nye 2007). (27) Oligopoly--including restrictions on entry through licensing, price controls, and mandatory inspections--led to larger and more dominant enterprises and made the political bargains easier to negotiate and maintain and the taxes easier to collect (Nye 2007). Changes in the tariffs toward pure free trade after 1850 required not only a belief in the national benefits of a more liberal policy, but also a willingness to overturn a long-standing prejudice against the French. Freer trade also depended on a willingness to challenge industries that would be threatened by imports and to accept the fiscal consequences of reduced tariffs while preserving the fiscal soundness that had made the British system the envy of Europe. The post-1815 decline in military spending was helpful in bringing this about, but the lower aggressiveness of British foreign policy too must be seen in the context of a changed international situation based on Enlightenment ideas.

In other areas, too, liberal ideology translated into policy changes. By the end of the 18th century monopolies were roundly condemned. (28) With the exception of the Bank of England, whose unique position was recognized by the British in the Bank Charter Act of 1844, they were phased out. (29) The East India Company's autonomy was weakened by Pitt's East India Act of 1784, which made the appointment of the Governor General the responsibility of the Crown and reserved all important policy decisions to a special committee controlled by the government. The Company's monopoly was ended by two parliamentary acts in 1813 and 1833, respectively. The position of the East India Company had weakened to the point that, after the 1857 rebellion, it lost its raison d'etre altogether.

On the whole, the European experience during the Industrial Revolution displays mixed evidence for Olson's famous hypothesis that political stability creates hotbeds for distributional coalitions to ripen and poison growth with their pernicious influence. In France and the Netherlands, the story rings true. Old coalitions were mercilessly swept away, and although new ones took their place, they were not nearly as effective in bringing about redistribution. Nowhere is this more clear-cut than in the fatal weakening of guilds and the abolition of internal trade barriers. Olson pointed to guilds as a classical case of a distributional coalition. Indeed, their disappearance in the late 18th century because of political disruption and border changes is consistent with his views. However, that leaves Great Britain, the leader of the Industrial Revolution, in an odd position. As noted, mercantilist views and the policies they supported declined in Britain after 1750, despite a remarkable ability of the regime to defend itself against radicalism on the left and reactionary Toryism on the right. To be sure, Britain did not need to outlaw guilds, abolish internal tariff barriers, or eliminate many of the "privileges" enjoyed by ruling classes over the continent. It did not have to instate the freedom of movement or occupational choice, release serfs, wholly reorganize the set-up of property rights over land to allow the rationalization of farming, unify bewildering sets of different local weights and measures, to say nothing of laws and litigation procedures and hundreds of encumbrances, small and large, on the free exercise of commerce and industry. For a meta-institution such as Parliament to be responsive to the changing needs of the economy, what was needed was a mechanism that signaled the needs of various sectors and industries to the members of Parliament. (30)

The growth of organized petitioning and lobbying matched the rise of Parliament in the 18th century and paralleled the concentration in the administrative structure that made London ever more central to the national bureaucracy. This meant that Londoners came to lobby and exert influence even on behalf of provincial interests (A. Olson 1992, p. 98). This influence peddling can be seen in the most important new source of excises for the 19th century--the brewing industry. As the regulation of beer shows, the British went from a system wherein anyone could get permission to brew and sell beer by petitioning (and often bribing) any of dozens of different judges with overlapping jurisdictions, to one in which a single judge held sway over a specific region or district, thus concentrating the political transactions that would take place. An Act of 1729 led to licenses being granted at licensing sessions known as Brewster Sessions in March of each year. The act also switched responsibility from the county to the local level by restricting jurisdiction for licensing to the local division (Webb and Webb 1903; London Metropolitan Archives 1998). The government discouraged entry and supported oligopoly in production, particularly as London rose to take a larger share of both the population and total commerce of the British national economy (Mathias 1959). It was not until the Beer Act of 1830 that the thrust of these regulations was reversed. From that point on, it became possible to sell liquor without obtaining licenses from a local magistrate, so long as a license was obtained from the Excise authorities (London Metropolitan Archives 1998; Nye 2007). Once the government decided to reduce its support for rent-seeking brewers, it could do so because it controlled a powerful political apparatus and did not have to be concerned with local opposition. Brewers thus represent a signal example of 18th century legislation that first strengthened local rent-seeking in a limited way and then abolished those rents once central authorities (in this case, the Excise) became well established.

Clearly, industrial and commercial interests found a way to reach the ears of Parliamentary notables and were able to overcome collective action problems with well-orchestrated petitioning campaigns. (31) The most important organized lobbies emerged later in the 18th century, such as the General Chamber of Manufacturers. Founded by iron manufacturer Samuel Garbett and potter Josiah Wedgwood, the General Chamber had standing committees of the most influential members of the trade, employed solicitors and parliamentary officials, and generated and circulated information pertinent to their case. When they felt they did not get a sympathetic hearing from the commons, they turned to the press and tried to influence public opinion. Garbett, a co-founder of the Carron ironworks in Scotland, can be regarded as one of the earliest professional political lobbyists. The ideological commitment of industrial lobbies to the principles of the Industrial Enlightenment is, of course, suspect. Their rhetoric, unsurprisingly, consistently used national interests, not the narrow interests of their trade, as the reason for their demand (Norris 1958). Given their superior knowledge of the details and their single-issue focus, however, their persuasive powers, as Adam Smith pointed out, were substantial.

Perhaps the most important and least noticed change in policy was the growing support for the bearers of technological progress and innovation. The British political establishment simply refused to cave in to the local special interests that tried to resist innovation in an attempt to preserve the technological status quo. The wool industry is a good example. It was initially far larger than cotton and had an ancient tradition of professional organization and regulation. Artisans and workers in the wool trades tried to manipulate the political establishment to protect their livelihood and somehow stop the new techniques of the preparation and finishing of wool fabrics. In 1776, workers in the wool industry petitioned the House of Commons and asked to suppress the jennies that threatened the livelihood of the "industrious poor," as they put it. It was a classic mercantilist argument, using "employment" as a pretext to request a rent-seeking constraint on economic activity. It was denied. In subsequent years, groups and lobbies repeatedly turned to Parliament, requesting the enforcement of old regulations or the introduction of new legislation that would hinder the machinery, but they too were turned down. In 1809, Parliament repealed the old laws regulating the employment practices of the wool industry. (32) In 1814, the ultimate blow came when Parliament repealed the 250-year-old Statute of Artificers, which had hindered free entry and unrestricted occupational choice for generations. (33) Challenges to law and order that could not be settled by local authorities were dealt with effectively and harshly. It could be maintained that the draconic Combination Acts passed in the 1790s acted in the same direction, although it is hard to view that repressive legislation as "progressive" or "enlightened" by our standards. Workers did not vote and had few options. It should thus be no surprise that there was little improvement in workers' living standards before 1850. What counted for the political elite was the growing conviction that technological progress was behind British success and the need to keep ahead in a competitive world.

What historical forces explain the decline of rent-seeking coalitions in Britain during the Industrial Revolution? Much like today, politics in 18th century Britain was a mixture of narrow interests and ideological convictions. Members of Parliament were increasingly influenced by Enlightenment ideas and their proudest offspring, liberal Political Economy. Parliament had long resisted general legislation based on ideology (Langford 1991, p. 156). In the 1780s, the influence of the new ideology on policy becomes discernible, as the liberal concepts of Charles Davenant, Josiah Child, David Hume, Josiah Tucker, Adam Smith, and similar Enlightenment thinkers on political economy influenced Shelburne, William Pitt the younger, William Eden (Lord Auckland), and their colleagues into formulating more liberal trade policies toward Ireland and France. The growing power of the parliamentary system meant that British institutions could adapt to changing circumstances and, equally important, to changing ideas. That there were rigidities is obvious. Yet the political system in Britain was reformed mostly without violence, without undue waste and destruction, and without tossing out the proverbial babies with the bath water. (34) The position of Parliament as a meta-institution meant that rent-seeking could be reformed and weakened as needed without bloodshed. Reforms were gradual in that they often preserved many older forms while "reforming" them to make them more suitable to changing needs. These reforms were certainly uneven and lagged behind the demand for them. However, the political structure that had emerged after 1688, while far from perfect, was better than any of Britain's continental neighbors and helped cement its economic leadership for much of the 19th century.

In many ways, the story of a growing British state that did not abuse its powers too severely, that cooperated in political reform, and that did not stand in the way of socially disruptive technological change is one of the most interesting and most Olsonian tales in all of modern economic history.

References

Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson. 2005. Institutions as a fundamental cause of economic growth. In The handbook of economic growth, edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 385-465.

Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2000. Political losers as a barrier to economic development. American Economic Review 90(2): 126-30.

Alder, Kenneth. 1995. A revolution to measure: The political economy of the metric system in France. In The values of precision, edited by M. Norton Wise. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Allen, Robert A. 1992. Enclosure and the yeoman: The agricultural development of the South Midlands, 1450-1850. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Ashton, T. S. 1924. Iron and steel in the industrial revolution. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

Blackstone, William. 1765-1769. Commentaries on the laws of England, 1st edition. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Bogart, Dan. 2005. Turnpike trusts and the transportation revolution in 18th century England. Explorations in Economic History 42:479-508.

Bogart, Dan, and Gary Richardson. 2006. Parliament and property rights in England: 1600-1815. Unpublished paper, University of California Irvine.

Boldrin, Michele, and David K. Levine. 2005. Against intellectual monopoly. Accessed 1 May 2007. Available at http://www.dklevine.com/general/intellectual/against.htm.

Brewer, John. 1988. The sinews of power. War, money and the English state, 1688-1783. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.

Buchinsky, Moshe, and Ben Polak. 1993. The emergence of a national capital market in England, 1710-1880. Journal of Economic History 53:1-24.

Cox, Gary. 1986. The development of a party-oriented electorate in England, 1832-1918. Historical Social Research 41:2-37.

Crouzet, Francois. 2001. A history of the European economy, 1000-2000. Charlottesville and London: University of Virginia Press.

Earle, Peter. 1977. The worm of Defoe. New York: Atheneum.

Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., and Robert D. Tollison. 1981. Mercantilism as a rent-seeking society. College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., and Robert D. Tollison. 1997. Politicized economies: Monarchy, monopoly, and mercantilism. College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press,

Harris, Ron. 2000. Industrializing English law: Entrepreneurship and business organization, 1720-1844. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Hirschman, Albert O. 1977. The passions and the interests: Political arguments for capitalism before its triumph. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Hoppit, Julian. 1996. Patterns of parliamentary legislation, 1660-1800. The Historical Journal 39(1):109-31.

Howe, Anthony. 2002. Restoring free trade: The British experience, 1776-1873. In The political economy of the British historical experience, 1688-1914, edited by Donald Winch and Patrick O'Brien. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 193-213.

Langford, Paul. 1991. Public life and the propertied Englishman, 1689-1798. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

London Metropolitan Archives. 1998. Information leaflet No. 3: Licensed victuallers records, London.

Maitland, Frederic. 1911. The constitutional history of England. Cambridge, UK: University Press.

Mantoux, Paul. 1928. The industrial revolution in the eighteenth century. New York: Harper and Row,

Mathias, Peter. 1959. The brewing industry in England, 1700-1830. Cambridge, UK: University Press.

Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The gifts of Athena. Historical origins of the knowledge economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Mokyr, Joel. 2006. Mercantilism, the enlightenment, and the industrial revolution. In Eli F. Heckscher (1879-1952): A celebratory symposium, edited by Ronald Findlay, et al. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 269-303.

Mokyr, Joel. 2007. The market for ideas and the origins of economic growth in eighteenth century Europe. In Tijdschrift voor Sociale en Economische Gesehiedenis. In press.

Norris, J. M. 1958. Samuel Garbett and the early development of industrial lobbying in Great Britain. Economic History Review 10(3):450-60.

North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and change in economic history. New York: W.W. Norton.

North, Douglass C. 2006. Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

North, Douglass C., and Barry R. Weingast. 1989. Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History 49(4):803-32.

Nye, John V. C. 2007. War, wine, and taxes. The political economy of Anglo-French trade 1689-1900. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

O'Brien, Patrick K. 1994. Central government and the economy. In The economic history of Britain since 1700, edited by Roderick Floud and D. N. McCloskey. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 203-41.

O'Brien, Patrick K. 2002. Fiscal exceptionalism: Great Britain and its European rivals from civil war to triumph at Trafalgar and Waterloo. In The political economy of British historical experience 1688-1914, edited by Patrick K.

O'Brien and Philip A. Hunt. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 245-65.

O'Brien, Patrick K., and P. A. Hunt. 1993. "Data Prepared on English Revenues, 1485-1815." European State Finance Database, Accessed 1 May 2007. Available at http://www.le.ac.uk/hi/bon/ESFDB/frameset.html.

Olson, Alison Gilbert. 1992. Making the empire work: London and American interest groups 1690-1790. Cambridge. MA: Harvard University Press.

Olson, Mancur. 1982. The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Ormrod, David. 2003. The rise of commercial empires. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Pitt, William. 1808. Speeches of the right Honourable William Pitt in the House of Commons. London: Longman, Hurst, Rees, and Orme.

Plumb, J. H. 1967. The growth of political stability in England 1675-1725. London: Peregrine Books.

Randall, Adrian. 1991. Before the Luddites. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1992. The fruits of revolution: Property rights, litigation and French agriculture, 1700-1860. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Rubinstein, William D. 1981. Men of property: The very wealthy in Britain since the industrial revolution. London: Croom Helm.

Rubinstein, W. D. 1983. The end of 'old corruption' in Britain 1780-1860. Past and Present 101:55-86.

Smith, Adam. 1776. 1976. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations, edited by Edwin Carman. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Smollett, Tobias George. 1762. 2003. The adventures of Sir Launcelot Greaves. Whitefish, MT: Kessinger reprints.

Steuart, Sir James. 1767. 1998. An inquiry into the principles of political economy. Volume 1, edited by Andrew Skinner. Noboru Kobayashi, and Hiroshi Mizuta. Reprint. London: Picketing and Chatto.

Szostak, Rick. 1991. The role of transportation in the industrial revolution. Montreal: McGill's-Queen's University Press.

Tucker, Josiah. 1763. The case of going to war, for the sake of procuring, enlarging, or securing of trade, considered in a new light. London: R. and J. Dodsley; and L. Hawes, W. Clarke, and R. Collins.

Webb, Sidney, and Beatrice Webb. 1903. The history of liquor licensing in England principally from 1700 to 1830. London and New York: Longmans, Green and Co.

Wrightson, Keith. 2000. Earthly necessities: Economic lives in early modern Britain. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.

(1) Or, as he colorfully put it, "For a pair of diamond buckles perhaps, or for something as frivolous and useless, they exchanged the maintenance, or what is the same thing, the price of the maintenance of a thousand men for a year, and with it the whole weight and authority which it could give them. The buckles, however, were to be all their own and no other human creature was to have any share of them" (Smith 1776, Book 3, ch. IV, pp. 418-19; p. 437 in the Cannan edition). James Steuart (1767, p. 217) noted, "'When once a state begins to subsist by the consequences of industry, there is less danger to be apprehended from the power of the sovereign ... he finds himself so bound up by the laws of his political economy that every transgression of them runs him into new difficulties."

(2) The importance of a national competitive market in iron goods, textiles, pottery, and luxury goods to the economy forms the basis of the work of Szostak (1991), whose contrast between Britain and France illustrates what Britain could have looked like had it remained a patchwork of more or less insulated regions.

(3) For example, consider the description of 16th century British markets in Wrightson (2000, p. 95). Regular economic interaction was primarily within a few miles of one's residence, and the proliferation of local markets assured the survival of a fragmented system of monopolistic competition. Insofar as goods were traded over long distances, they were raw materials such as wool, coal, iron, leather, imported goods, or goods requiring a particularly high level of skill, such as Sheffield knives.

(4) "Far more influential, however, but less noticed was the steady growth of the home market and the gradual obliteration of local economic isolation. The development of inland navigation, through the canalization and control of rivers, had brought some of the most fertile and productive regions of England within easy and cheap reach of London and the great outposts.... Yet the growth of river navigation was not easily secured, and often it was impeded rather than helped by England's political system: The Cheshire MPs, for example, held up the Weaver navigation from 1699 to 1720. It was only in the 1720s that river navigation bills secured easy passages through the House of Commons." (Plumb 1967, p. 18)

(5) In the West of England wool industry, the competition with Yorkshire and the new machinery adopted there was particularly fierce. Differences in the way the industry was organized accounted for the strong resistance to the new techniques in Wiltshire and Gloucestershire, yet the integration of the markets by the 1790s meant that these niches had to either overcome their resistance or cede the industry to more progressive regions (Randall 1991).

(6) There is also growing evidence that factor markets were showing growing integration. For capital markets, this can be readily measured through the co-movement of interest rates in London with transactions in Yorkshire (Buchinsky and Polak 1993). Labor movement, settlement laws notwithstanding, was quite substantial. Although most of it was short-distance, it is estimated that between 1701 and 1831, London absorbed about 1.3 million immigrants from all over Britain. The counties of the Industrial Revolution experienced considerably faster growth than their natural rates of growth would suggest.

(7) Blackstone (1765-1769, Book 1, ch. 2, section III) stated categorically that, "It hath sovereign and uncontrollable authority in making, confirming, enlarging, restraining, abrogating, repealing, reviving, and expounding of laws, concerning matters of all possible denominations, ecclesiastical, or temporal, civil, military, maritime, or criminal." Langford feels that the British themselves only discovered this legitimacy in the second half of the 18th century and that "Blackstone himself seems almost to have been shocked by his discovery" (1991, p. 149).

(8) As Szostak has noted (1991, p. 89), the private bill was a unique institution and no other country had any similar device at its disposal at this time. The distinction, as Hoppit has pointed out (1996, pp. 116-7) is not very helpful. Instead, he proposes a distinction between "general" and "specific" or "local" bills. The latter constituted over 70% of all bills passed between 1660 and 1800.

(9) The total number of acts passed during the rules of Charles II and James II was 564, or 20 per annum. In the 25 years between the Bill of Rights and the Hanoverian ascension (1689 1714), this increased to 1752 or 70 per annum: by the period 1760-1800, this was 8351, or 209 per annum (see Hoppit 1996, p. 117).

(10) Maitland (1911, p. 383) felt that "one is inclined to call the last century [i.e., the 18th; his lecture was written in 1886] the century of privilegia. [Parliament] seems afraid to rise to the dignity of a general proposition ... it deals with this common and that marriage." Maitland felt that only after the reform act of 1832 did Parliament start to "legislate for the whole country," but this ignores much important legislation in the 18th century, although the frequency of specific and private acts declined in the 19th century.

(11) Well into the 19th century, many officeholders were selected purely for their political influence with absolutely no regard to their qualifications for the post. In many instances there was not even the apparent need to fulfill the most basic or nominal duties. Among the numerous examples he cited, "Lord Auckland, who received 1,400 [pounds sterling] per annum as Vendue-Master at Demarara, 'where he had never been,' and 1,900 [pounds sterling] per annum as 'Auditor at Greenwich Hospital,' in its words 'for doing nothing,' as he certainly never audited" (Rubinstein 1983, p. 66). It even extended to academia, where Nassau Senior's resignation from the Oxford Chair of Political Economy in 1829 led to the election of Richard Whateley, who had no qualifications except for being a prominent Christian who wished to rescue economics "permanently from disrepute" (p. 68).

(12) It might be added, however, that throughout the 18th century, much of local justice was still in the hands of unpaid justices of the peace, and it remains an open question how accurate the accusations of corruption really are (as, for example, in Smollett's fictional Justice Gobble in Launcelot Greaves, published in 1762).

(13) Even patently local interests found it increasingly necessary to masquerade as national interests. Thus, the Newcastle coal owners lobbied against internal waterways that threatened the price of seaborne coal, arguing that coastal shipping provided the navy with a supply of recruits. The promoters of the canals argued the reverse, that inland navigation would provide a nursery for seamen (Langford 1991, p. 204).

(14) See especially Ormrod (2003): O'Brien (1994; 2002).

(15) Jean Laurent Rosenthal (1992) has argued that it was precisely in the area of public works and coordination that the French ancien regime failed.

(16) The British system (especially measures of volume) still left a lot to be desired, even after the Winchester bushel was made the national measure of volume in 1713 (confusingly set to eight gallons for grains and eight gallons and quarter for coal) and the barrel set as the national measure of drinks (34 gallons in 1688 but changed to 36 in 1803) (Hoppit 1993). Although it seems that the majority of transactions were conducted with the use of standardized measures and weights, enough local variants were still in use to concern many contemporaries and to instigate some Parliamentary inquiries.

(17) Rubinstein's rather heroic estimate of landed and nonlanded millionaires and half-millionaires dying between 1809 and 1859 shows 179 landed millionaires versus 10 nonlanded millionaires and 338 landed, compared with 54 nonlanded, half-millionaires (1981, pp. 60-65). As Rubinstein (p. 61) remarks, "an observer entering a room full of Britain's 200 wealthiest men in 1825 might be forgiven for thinking that the Industrial Revolution had not occurred."

(18) An example of what was meant by patronage and influence is the following case: The Vice-Chancellor of Cambridge University, for example, sometimes sent the marshal of the University to the licensed lodging housekeepers to recommend a candidate, and in 1834 pointedly deferred the day for renewing licenses until after the parliamentary by-election held that year. One of the most common forms of influence was the practice of dealing exclusively with the shopkeepers who had voted "correctly" and of withdrawing custom from those who had not (Cox 1986, p. 212).

(19) Cox attributes patronage decline to civil service reforms that eliminated direct appointments (1820) and then opened up civil service employment to direct competition in 1853 and 1870 (Cox 1986, p. 209).

(20) As Cox notes: For most of the first half of the [19th] century, private bill committees consisted chiefly of members directly interested in the measures referred to them. In 1844, however, the Commons began to staff their railway bill committees exclusively with impartial members, and this practice was extended to all other private bills in 1855. Each member chosen for private bill committee service was thereafter required to sign a declaration "that his constituents have no local interest, and that he has no personal interest" in the bill to be considered (Cox 1986, p. 210).

(21) Some of the following is based on Mokyr (2006).

(22) Even as sensible an observer as Daniel Defoe, writing in 1704, thought that "by how much the trade, and consequently the wealth of France is encreased for the past 150 years past, by so much the trade and wealth of England, Holland, Spain, Flanders, and the rest of trading Europe has decreased" (Earle 1977, p. 91). Adam Smith summed up this view scathingly: "nations having been taught that their interest consisted of beggaring their neighbours. Each nation has been made to look with an invidious eye upon the prosperity of all the nations with which it trades, and to consider their gain as its own loss" (1976, p. 519).

(23) Among those, particularly brazen attempts to enrich a few at the expense of the public at large were the Calicot Acts of 1701 and 1721, unceremoniously tossed out in 1774, and the 1733 Molasses Act, intended to protect British sugar plantations on its Caribbean Islands, which raised the ire of Samuel Adams and his fellow revolutionaries and was abandoned during the American Revolution. The famous Bubble Act of 1720, too, was a thinly disguised attempt by incumbent firms to place new entrants at a disadvantage and thus secure an exclusionary rent. Harris points out (2000, p. 135) that the main barrier to entry into the state of joint-stock enterprise was not so much convincing Parliament to vote a private incorporation bill, but acquiring the money needed to overcome resistance from incumbent firms or other vested interests.

(24) Josiah Tucker thought that nothing was so absurd as going to war for the sake of getting trade. "Trade will always follow cheapness, not conquest," he argued (1763, p. 41). In its stead, 18th century thinkers proposed the concept of doux commerce, gentle trade, a concept popularized by Montesquieu in which a peaceful, mutually advantageous exchange in a "civilized consortium of nations" enriched and improved all participants (Howe 2002, p. 195). Indeed, the hope was that "the natural effect of commerce is to lead to peace," with calculated interests overcoming the passions of war (Hirschman 1977, pp. 79-80).

(25) of the law prohibiting the emigration of skilled artisans, Ashton in his classic work (1924, p. 205) wrote that, "by this time [1824] the crude nationalism of the eighteenth century had begun to lose ground before the assault of newer ideas of personal freedom."

(26) "It is a maxim in trade, no Kingdom can flourish by their commerce when Weight and Measure are not certain" stated one mid-18th century writer (cited by Hoppit 1993, p. 91). But adopting the radical (and "republican") French innovation of metric weights and measures was never considered a serious option in Britain, though it had some supporters. As in other areas, the French revolution itself a child of the Enlightenment--was ironically highly disruptive of the salutary effects of the British Enlightenment on the economy.

(27) The beverage interests had been essential to the fiscal transformation of the 18th century. Wine tariffs kept out a French product that might compete with British and colonial beverages. Tariffs were used to regulate trade from the Continent in favor of British colonial rum, beer, and whiskey at home and the wines and liquors of Portugal abroad. Limited competition from imports allowed the maintenance of high excises on beer and other domestic alcoholic beverages.

(28) Adam Smith (1976, p. 165) called them the "great enemy of good management," and writers from William Godwin to Josiah Tucker treated them as an unmitigated social evil. Liberal views had become the bases for policy.

(29) The Bank of England was gradually converted into a public policy tool to manage the economy into greater stability. That, too, was the result of the declining acceptability of rent-seeking and the growing awareness of the need for enlightened government management.

(30) In the 18th century, we observe the emergence of the lobbying of Parliament as a coherent and coordinated activity. In the work of Alison Olson (1992), we see the rise of focused interest groups that begin in the late 17th century and develop to the fullest in the 18th. Even though Olson's work is primarily focused on colonial interest groups, her observations are often germane to all such coalitions in the 18th century. She observed that these interests "expected favors: anything from favorable legislation and beneficial trade treaties at one extreme, to administrative concessions and financial assistance on pet projects at the other" (A. Olson 1992, p. 95).

(31) In 1718, the leather industry submitted no fewer than 91 separate petitions to get its point across (Hoppit 1996, p. 128).

(32) The language used by the committee is telling: "If Parliament had acted on such principles [on which the use of these particular machines is objected to] 50 years ago, the Woollen Manufacture would never have attained to half its present size ... its Augmentation is principally to be ascribed to the general spirit of enterprize and industry among a free and enlightened people.... It is likewise an important consideration ... that we are at this day surrounded by powerful and civilized Nations, who are intent on cultivating their Manufactures and pushing their Commerce." See Great Britain, B.P.P. 1806 No. 3 ("Select Committee on State of Woollen Manufacture of England"), p. 7.

(33) As Paul Mantoux put it well many years ago, "Whether [the] resistance was instinctive or considered, peaceful or violent, it obviously had no chance of success" (Mantoux 1928, p. 408).

(34) Parliament could even engage in local violations of property rights if these were considered necessary for the public good (e.g., when land needed to be confiscated for transport projects) or when it deemed certain property rights to be incompatible with Enlightenment notions, such as the slave trade (abolished in 1807) and slavery altogether (abolished in the British colonies in 1833).

Joel Mokyr, Department of Economics, Northwestern University, 2003 Sheridan Road, Evanston, IL 60208, USA and Berglas School of Economics, Tel Aviv University, Tel Aviv. Israel; E-mail j-mokyr@northwestern.edu: corresponding author.

John V. C. Nye, Department of Economics, Washington University, One Brookings Drive, St. Louis, MO 63130.


COPYRIGHT 2007 Southern Economic Association Reproduced with permission of the copyright holder. Further reproduction or distribution is prohibited without permission.
Copyright 2007, Gale Group. All rights reserved. Gale Group is a Thomson Corporation Company.
NOTE: All illustrations and photos have been removed from this article.

Blog Archive